Risk is not empirically correlated with return

post by jsalvatier · 2010-11-22T05:31:59.316Z · LW · GW · Legacy · 28 comments

Contents

  Added some (hopefully) clarifying material:
None
28 comments

The most widely appreciated finance theory is the Capital Asset Pricing Model. It basically says that diminishing marginal utility of absolute wealth implies that riskier financial assets should have higher expected returns than less risky assets and that only risk correlated with the market (beta risk) is a whole is important because other risk can be diversified out.

Eric Falkenstein argues that the evidence does not support this theory; that the riskiness of assets (by any reasonable definition) is not positively correlated with return (some caveats apply). He has a paper (long but many parts are skimmable; not peer reviewed; also on SSRN) as well as a book on the topic. I recommend reading parts of the paper.

The gist of his competing theory is that people care mostly about relative gains rather than absolute gains. This implies that riskier financial assets will not have higher expected returns than less risky assets. People will not require a higher return to hold assets with higher undiversifiable variance because everyone is exposed to the same variance and people only care about their relative wealth.

Falkenstein has a substantial quantity of evidence to back up his claim. I am not sure if his competing theory is correct, but I find the evidence against the standard theory quite convincing.

If risk is not correlated with returns, then anyone who is mostly concerned with absolute wealth can profit from this by choosing a low beta risk portfolio.

This topic seems more appropriate for the discussion section, but I am not completely sure, so if people think it belongs in the main area, let me know.

Added some (hopefully) clarifying material:

All this assumes that you eliminate idiosyncratic risk through diversification. Technically impossible, but you can get it reasonably low. The R's are all *instantaneous* returns; though since these are linear models they apply to geometrically accumulated returns as well. The idea that E(R_asset) are independent of past returns is a background assumption for both models and most of finance.

Beta_portfolio = Cov(R_portfolio, R_market)/variance(R_market)

In CAPM your expected and variance are:

E(R_portfolio) = R_rfree + Beta_portfolio * (E(R_market) - R_rfree)
Var(R_portfolio) = Beta_portfolio * Var(R_market)

in Falkenstein's model your expected return are:

E(R_portfolio) = R_market       # you could also say = R_rfree; the point is that its a constant
Var(R_portfolio) = Beta_portfolio * Var(R_market)

The major caveat being that it doesn't apply very close to Beta_portfolio = 0; Falkenstein attributes this to liquidity benefits. And it doesn't apply to very high Beta_portfolio; he attributes this to "buying hope". See the paper for more.

Falkenstein argues that his model fits the facts more closely than CAPM. Assuming Falkenstein's model describes reality, if your utility declines with rising Var(R_portfolio) (the standard assumption), then you'll want to hold a portfolio with a beta of zero; or taking into account the caveats, a low Beta_portfolio. If your utility is declining with Var(R_portfolio - R_market), then you'll want to hold the market portfolio. Both of these results are unambiguous since there's no trade off between either measure of risk and return.

Some additional evidence from another source, and discussion: http://falkenblog.blogspot.com/2010/12/frazzini-and-pedersen-simulate-beta.html

28 comments

Comments sorted by top scores.

comment by Nisan · 2010-11-22T09:41:00.910Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Things I learned from this post:

  • When one says "riskier assets should have higher expected returns than less risky assets", one imagines comparing two assets that cost the same because the demand for them is the same.

  • "Relative gains" means gains relative to everyone else.

(I don't have any substantial comments to make; I'm just closing the language barrier.)

Replies from: ESRogs
comment by ESRogs · 2020-08-22T17:37:56.740Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

When one says "riskier assets should have higher expected returns than less risky assets", one imagines comparing two assets that cost the same because the demand for them is the same.

Not sure if you'll remember what you meant 10 years ago, but... what did you mean by "cost the same"?

When you compare the returns you're normalizing by the number of dollars put in, so you're not comparing one share price directly to another or something like that. And if you measure cost relative to assets, or present value of expected future profits, then the claim is that they do not cost the same -- that the riskier asset costs less.

I guess if you think of cost as compared to risk-adjusted return, then yes you're expecting them to cost the same in those terms (and that's why the riskier asset with the same expected return costs less in nominal terms). Is that what was meant, or something else?

Replies from: Nisan
comment by Nisan · 2020-08-24T07:42:45.810Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Hm, I think all I meant was:

"If you have two assets with the same per-share price, and asset A's value per share has a higher variance than asset B's value per share, then asset A's per-share value must have a higher expectation than asset B's per-share value."

I guess I was using "cost" to mean "price" and "return" to mean "discounted value or earnings or profit".

comment by timtyler · 2010-11-22T22:56:12.923Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

If risk is not correlated with returns, then anyone who is mostly concerned with absolute wealth can profit from this by choosing a low beta risk portfolio.

That sounds as though it would only work if risk was negatively-correlated with returns.

Replies from: jsalvatier, CronoDAS
comment by jsalvatier · 2010-11-23T02:34:05.475Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Surprisingly not. If returns are uncorrelated with risk, then you choose a low beta portfolio. It will have low overall variance. You can either choose to have a a low variance portfolio with the same expected return as the market portfolio or you can use leverage (doesn't necessarily require personally taking out loans) to have a higher variance, higher expected return portfolio. Whichever you prefer.

Replies from: SilasBarta
comment by SilasBarta · 2010-11-23T17:55:51.297Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

If returns are uncorrelated with risk (average gain in value of an investment is unrelsated to its volatility), why would you choose the low beta portfolio? Couldn't you increase your personal returns by dollar-cost-averaging into the high-beta portfolio?

Replies from: jsalvatier
comment by jsalvatier · 2010-11-24T03:46:36.592Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Do you have your directions flipped? beta = covariance(portfolio, market)/variance(market) if beta is low for a portfolio, it has low covariance with the market. If not, I don't understand your logic.

A high beta portfolio will have high variance. If risk is not correlated with return, then it won't have higher expected return to compensate, which is worse than having the same return and low variance.

Replies from: SilasBarta
comment by SilasBarta · 2010-11-24T04:21:44.422Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

I was taking beta to effectively measure average deviation from a trendline exp(k t), k>0, when an investment's cumulative value is expressed in dollars. In any case, that's the measure of risk I thought you were using, and by that definition of it, I think I've shown it to indicate a way you can make returns greater than k: just buy $X worth of the investment every period (dollar-cost averaging). In that case, you will buy less of the investment when it is above exp(k t) trend and more when it's below, beating the ROR k.

This would show how investors buying riskier assets would end up with a higher return for the same average return k.

Replies from: jsalvatier
comment by jsalvatier · 2010-11-24T05:12:52.472Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

I'd think average deviation of portfolio value from any trendline will be infinite for any risky portfolio, assuming asset prices are a random walk. Your story relies on mean reverting asset returns, and the advantage from that mean reversion rather than Falkenstein's idea.

Normally, discussions about correlations between assets are actually discussions of correlations between returns of assets.

Replies from: SilasBarta
comment by SilasBarta · 2010-11-24T16:57:57.906Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

I'd think average deviation of portfolio value from any trendline will be infinite for any risky portfolio, assuming asset prices are a random walk.

How can that be, when you take the average per unit time.

In any case, I'm confused -- I had always taken "risk" in this context to mean the volatility, and the traditional argument to mean that the highest-returning risky assets should have higher returns than the highest-returning less-risky assets. And my point is that the individual's return will be different from that of the asset's return.

Replies from: jsalvatier
comment by jsalvatier · 2010-11-24T18:00:18.458Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Do you mean average change in deviation from the trend line? I understood you to mean average absolute deviation from the trend line. Maybe I just misunderstood you. The average change in deviation is non-infiinite, but the average absolute deviation deviation will grow without bound.

Replies from: SilasBarta
comment by SilasBarta · 2010-11-24T20:21:26.596Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Sorry, I meant the signed difference -- so that an investment going above and below could count as zero. But I don't think that's essential to my point about risk per the standard definition.

Replies from: jsalvatier
comment by jsalvatier · 2010-11-24T22:52:00.698Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

I think you're confused about something, but I'm not sure what it is. I've added some clarifying material to the post. Does that clarify our discussion?

Replies from: SilasBarta
comment by SilasBarta · 2010-11-26T20:56:20.764Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Given as it doesn't address any of the issues I raised (like the difference between investor returns and investment returns), no.

Replies from: jsalvatier
comment by jsalvatier · 2010-11-26T22:26:04.405Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Maybe I didn't make it clear, but difference between investor returns and investment returns is a non-issue, because such models are about instantaneous/incremental returns, not total returns. The simplest way to think about it is to split up time into segments. At the start of each segment you construct your portfolio (which could include cash) and it stays constant over that segment. At the end of the segment you observe the return to your portfolio over that period. The geometric sum of these returns is going to be your total return. Both CAPM and Falkestein's model are about these period returns, not total returns. They are also only about the change in value beginning to end; the Var() does not describe the back and forth motion during the period, it describes your uncertainty at the beginning of the period about what the end of the period is going to look like.

I think maybe I understand what you were saying in the beginning. I'll explain that and why I think it's wrong, and you tell me if I've misunderstood something. I'm taking your first post to indicate your core point; if it's changed, tell me.

OK, so I think what your idea is that your idea was that beta is like the variance of a portfolio price around a path. You can profit from this by buying when it's below the path since this implies the price will at some point be above the path, giving you a profit.

The problem with is that financial markets are pretty efficient. This means that prices are a random walk, meaning the expected incremental return on an asset is independent of past returns. The price of an asset being below trend does not imply that above average expected incremental returns. You can think of this as saying that any changes in a portfolio price are permanent; if a stock price goes down, on average, it's going to stay down; it might go up, but it's just as likely to go down further.

Replies from: SilasBarta
comment by SilasBarta · 2010-11-27T00:46:14.448Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

1) I care about the investor return, not the asset return or any of the other metrics you listed, because that's the return I get.

2) I wasn't suggesting that an investor could buy on the lows. I was saying that the investor could buy in every period, but only an amount that is constant in dollar terms (or in terms of some other risk-free asset). This would then exceed the asset's average return, though both might be negative.

Replies from: jsalvatier, jsalvatier
comment by jsalvatier · 2010-11-27T01:20:49.059Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

1) Obviously you're concered about invstor return (well utility anyway), I never intended to suggested there was any other metric you'd be interested in. Surely our previous conversations should have convinced you I'm not one to make that kind of mistake frequently.

2) Dollar cost averaging gets you something if there's mean reversion. Otherwise it gains you nothing (might not cost you anything either) for the simple reason that asset prices are random walks. This is a standard result (http://www.moneychimp.com/features/dollar_cost.htm). If you think Falkenstein's model implies that dollar cost averaging is a superior strategy, then I think you've misunderstood something. I'm not sure what it is though, I tried to reexplain the concepts which I thought you might be misunderstanding. Could you reexplain why you think it would get you superior performance using the kind of multi period model I was talking about?

Replies from: SilasBarta
comment by SilasBarta · 2010-12-07T00:09:19.229Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Okay, I hadn't actually experimented with the math on that so I can't defend DCA as amplifying returns under volatility. So I don't have much more to say in objection to the result you've posted either.

comment by jsalvatier · 2010-11-27T01:31:45.774Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

1) I'm not sure what different metrics you though I suggested. To clarify, CAPM and Falkenstein's model are about returns for a constant portfolio over a given period. If you want to talk about a changing portfolio, you'll have to approximate this as several time periods each with a different constant portolio and geomtrically average the returns.

comment by CronoDAS · 2010-11-23T05:04:42.815Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Actually, IIRC, one of Falkenstein's findings was that once volatility exceeds a certain level, it actually is negatively correlated with returns. He explains this with the phrase "People pay for hope."

Replies from: timtyler
comment by timtyler · 2010-11-23T08:23:12.823Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Not terribly surprising - though you can pretty easily turn a low risk investment into a high-risk one at relatively low cost with a roulette wheel. It is going to be harder to sell high-risk low return bonds when high-risk average return bonds are also available.

comment by Dan_Moore · 2010-11-23T20:45:58.002Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Falkenstein seems to change the definition of 'risk-free'; for him, risk-free means investing in the whole market?

Replies from: CronoDAS, jsalvatier
comment by CronoDAS · 2010-11-25T06:51:57.756Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Sort of. "Risk-free" always has to be defined relative to some baseline level of performance. You'd think that "hiding dollars in your mattress" would be risk-free (as long as you don't get robbed), because the value of your "investment", measured in dollars, won't go down. On the other hand, what if you stuffed your mattress with euros instead of dollars? Now the value of your investment, as measured in euros, won't change, but the value of your investment, measured in dollars, can. (And you could also measure the value of your investment in terms of its ability to buy ounces of gold, bushels of wheat, barrels of oil, McDonalds hamburgers, Google shares, kilowatt-hours of electricity, or even hours of human labor.)

Normally, people who study investing assume that people care about "absolute wealth" and use either dollars or U.S. treasury bills as their "risk-free" benchmark, but Falkenstein is saying that this doesn't reflect the actual behavior of the people who manage most of the money in the economy. Falkenstein says that they act as though they care not about "absolute wealth" but "relative wealth": their performance compared to other investors. After all, if everybody lost a lot of money, it's clearly not your fault the fund lost all that value, so you get to keep your job. And even if you're making money, you'll lose clients if other people happen to be making a lot more. Basically, only deviations from average market returns (as measured by the S&P 500) are rewarded or punished, so the "risk-free" thing for them to do is to act like an index fund and end up with exactly "average" returns.

comment by jsalvatier · 2010-11-24T04:02:38.266Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

I wouldn't say "for him"; he advises people to choose a low beta portfolio, but yes, in the model he uses to explain the data investing in the market portfolio is risk free.

Replies from: Dan_Moore
comment by Dan_Moore · 2010-11-24T15:22:46.692Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

I would say 'for him' because 'Falkenstein risk-free' <> 'risk-free' as is commonly used. (For example, anyone invested in the whole market the last few years knows that it's not risk-free in the literal or commonly used sense.) As a result, 'Falkenstein risk premium' <> 'risk premium' as commonly used. I think if he had used a different term, like baseline or benchmark for example (instead of recycling/ humptifying the existing term 'risk free') his article would be clearer.

Replies from: Dan_Moore
comment by Dan_Moore · 2010-11-24T16:18:45.307Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Falkenstein violates the second of what I think of as the Two Commandments of Research:

  1. If a name for a concept exists in the literature, you use it; you don't create your own name for a concept that's already in currency. If your concept is one-off (i.e., related, but somehow different) from an existing concept, it's best to coin a term which is a modification of the current term.

  2. Thou shalt never clobber an existing term by giving it a new meaning different from its existing meaning. Ever.

Replies from: CronoDAS
comment by CronoDAS · 2010-11-25T06:56:09.859Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

Should you still call a triangle a triangle if you're drawing it on a curved surface?

(You're right in general, though.)

Replies from: Sniffnoy
comment by Sniffnoy · 2010-11-25T07:40:43.005Z · LW(p) · GW(p)

I suppose extending is a case of "giving it a new meaning different from its existing meaning", but it isn't clobbering.