Posts

CFAR's 2019 Fundraiser 2019-12-30T00:03:10.040Z
Misapplied economics and overwrought estimates 2015-01-12T17:10:50.617Z
How much does consumption affect production? 2015-01-05T15:51:20.824Z

Comments

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on The Mind: Board Game Review · 2020-06-19T18:05:13.963Z · LW · GW

The group I played with (same as Mark Xu's group from comment above) decided that "S2 counting is illegal (you have to let your gut 'feel' the right amount of time)" and "repeating some elaborate ritual that takes the same amount of time before your card is due is illegal" (e.g. you can stick your hand 10% of the way towards the pile when the number's 10 off from your card, and 50% of the way when it's 5 off.)

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on We run the Center for Applied Rationality, AMA · 2019-12-22T17:43:39.013Z · LW · GW

Metaphors We Live By by George Lakoff — Totally changed the way I think about language and metaphor and frames when I read it in college. Helped me understand that there are important kinds of knowledge that aren't explicit.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on We run the Center for Applied Rationality, AMA · 2019-12-22T05:18:33.397Z · LW · GW

What I get from Duncan’s FB post is (1) an attempt to disentangle his reputation from CFAR’s after he leaves, (2) a prediction that things will change due to his departure, and (3) an expression of frustration that more of his knowledge than necessary will be lost.

  1. It's a totally reasonable choice.
  2. At the time I first saw Duncan’s post I was more worried about big changes to our workshops from losing Duncan than I have observed since then. A year later I think the change is actually less than one would expect from reading Duncan’s post alone. That doesn’t speak to the cost of not having Duncan—since filling in for his absence means we have less attention to spend on other things, and I believe some things Duncan brought have not been replaced.
  3. I am also sad about this, and believe that I was the person best positioned to have caused a better outcome (smaller loss of Duncan’s knowledge and values). In other words I think Duncan’s frustration is not only understandable, but also pointing at a true thing.
Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on We run the Center for Applied Rationality, AMA · 2019-12-21T19:32:48.375Z · LW · GW

All of these answers so far (Luke, Adam, Duncan) resonate for me.

I want to make sure I’m hearing you right though, Duncan. Putting aside the ‘yes’ or ‘no’ of the original question, do the scenes/experiences that Luke and Adam describe match what you remember from when you were here?

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on We run the Center for Applied Rationality, AMA · 2019-12-21T17:02:50.491Z · LW · GW

Agreed I wouldn’t take the ratanon post too seriously. For another example, I know from living with Dario that his motives do not resemble those ascribed to him in that post.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on CFAR: Progress Report & Future Plans · 2019-12-19T20:51:23.173Z · LW · GW

+1 (I'm the Executive Director of CFAR)

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on Misapplied economics and overwrought estimates · 2015-01-15T07:24:57.534Z · LW · GW

What do you recommend if good data is too costly to collect?

I think that if someone has made a claim but failed to use good data or an empirical model, it should not require good data or an empirical model to convince that person that they were wrong. Great if you have it, but I'm not going to ignore an argument just because it fails to use a model.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-15T07:17:22.896Z · LW · GW

I agree with your definitions of the two curves, although I don't know what point you're making by the distinction.

In either case we can ask, "how much will changes in demand affect equilibrium quantity?" In a constant-cost industry, the answer will be 1:1 in the long-run (as indicated by a flat, or infinitely elastic long-run supply curve), but as you gradually shorten the scope over which you're looking at the market, making it a shorter- and shorter-run supply curve, it will steepen (elasticity decrease) such that the answer is "less than 1:1".

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on Misapplied economics and overwrought estimates · 2015-01-15T07:05:27.857Z · LW · GW

Great! This is the only 'complete' argument I've seen that our prior for animal products industries should be that they are increasing-cost rather than constant-cost. I'm not as confident as you seem to be, but that's more of a quibble at this point, and I'm glad we agree on the meta-prior!

The challenge then is to convince Norwood and Lusk that we want to know the long-run impact of consumer choices on animal production, not the short-run! They're clearly estimating short-run elasticities since (a) their supply curves are way too steep, even for an increasing-cost industry, and (b) they explain their elasticities with an explanation that is irrelevant to the long-run:

Because it takes a year between the time a cow is bred and the time her calf is born, and then it also takes a long period before that cow can be transformed into beef or produce milk, it is difficult for beef and dairy producers to alter production according to changes in consumer preferences.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on Misapplied economics and overwrought estimates · 2015-01-13T22:43:36.934Z · LW · GW

Given our confidence for opposing positions and your credentials my best guess is that there's a miscommunication, in which case my guess on your correctness won't be well defined. Perhaps there's some critical word I'm using colloquially that has an importantly different meaning in economics.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on Misapplied economics and overwrought estimates · 2015-01-13T21:32:13.288Z · LW · GW

The most important factor of production in haircuts is human labour. If you double the population of a country, then you double the number of haircuts demanded, but you also double the amount of labour supplied.

To get around the objection of increasing labor, let's assume instead that everyone in the country decides to permanently get their hair cut twice as often as before. What do you expect the real price of haircuts to be in 10 years? Significantly higher, about the same, or significantly less? My prior is "about the same" until I have more data.

More generally (and naively), if I had to guess whether a given industry is increasing-, constant-, or decreasing-cost, two factors I would consider are: 1) How important to the cost of the product are inputs that are finite? How much of the market for those inputs goes toward making the product (as opposed to other uses that might substitute away from that input if the price increases)? 2) What economies of scale exist in the production of the product? To what extent will greater demand-per-person allow firms to approach the maximally efficient scale?

I have not seen these (or other relevant) factors used to advocate that animal product industries in particular should be assumed to be increasing-cost. (However I do appreciate your attempt to argue that our prior should be that all industries are increasing-cost in the absence of better evidence, which I argue against in a separate comment.)

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on Misapplied economics and overwrought estimates · 2015-01-13T21:11:36.902Z · LW · GW

Given your credentials, I can't fathom you disagree that shifts in demand can cause shifts in the short-run supply curve in the long-run. E.g. if lots of people start/stop eating meat, the short-run supply curve will look different 5 years from now due to that change alone.

Given that I believe you agree with that, I deduce that you only mean that changes in demand cannot shift the short-run supply curve in the short-run, nor shift the long-run supply curve in the long-run. With that I do agree by definition.

Funny that the only post by someone acknowledging negative-sloping long-run supply curves AND refraining from advocating a prior that meat industries are increasing-cost (yay; that's all I really want!) ends up sounding like a disagreement anyway due to semantics : ]

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on Misapplied economics and overwrought estimates · 2015-01-13T20:57:25.877Z · LW · GW

You're the first person who disagrees with my conclusion but is willing to admit that some industries will be decreasing-cost (wherein we should expect greater than 1:1 effect on production); that is very refreshing!

in the extreme, every industry is increasing-cost, simply because of resource scarcity (consider the situation if computer game demand was so high that 90% of the population worked as game developers).

Yes, I agree in the extremely-large case. What about the extremely-small case? It's very hard to think of a fledgling market for which the average price would be higher if the market produced 100 units instead of 1 unit. So I think that the vast majority of markets will be decreasing-cost when they're arbitrarily small, and increasing-cost when they're arbitrarily large. What about in between? How do we know where on the spectrum an industry is?

I agree we need a prior. If something could be positive, neutral, or negative, and I have no evidence of which it is, my default meta-prior is neutral. Obviously that is an extremely weak prior (ie I'm very open to being convinced it should be something else), but nothing in the pieces I quoted justifies an increasing-cost prior (they just discuss short-run market dynamics). Your "low hanging fruit" argument comes the closest because it's a valid reason that points in one direction, but it is incompletely argued so far (the "in the extreme" argument is unconvincing since the same can be said of an opposing force).

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on Misapplied economics and overwrought estimates · 2015-01-13T16:40:32.974Z · LW · GW

The default assumption is that industries are increasing-cost, because low-hanging fruit is picked first.

I agree this effect will push towards an increasing-cost industry, but there are other effects at play that might be even more powerful such that the industry is constant- or decreasing-cost. For an extreme example, consider the market for computer games; I expect this to be a decreasing-cost industry (the more people buy computer games, the cheaper-per-quality they will be in the long-run, even ignoring technology improvements). For a more moderate example consider haircuts. How confident are you that the price of haircuts will increase the more haircuts there are in the long-run? For example, do you expect the real price of haircuts to rise dramatically as the population of a country grows dramatically? I do not.

My claim is that we shouldn't assume that the meat industries are increasing-cost unless/until we have better reason to do so. The rationalist community pieces implicitly assume that all industries are increasing-cost (and don't give reasoning for that example that's relevant in the long-run), whereas the economics articles I cite show that industries can also be constant- or decreasing-cost as well.

The rationalist community, and standard economics, give the same answer, and it is only your very strange assumption (which you bury in the middle of your article!) that causes a discrepancy.

Actually my prior that industries are constant-cost is not a particularly strong one; I'd be happy if the sources I cite simply remove or justify their assumption that animal product industries in particular are increasing-cost. As I've shown from the standard economics citations, they are actually with me in not assuming that industries are increasing-cost (unless you're arguing that AmosWEB and Policonomics do not represent the standard economics view).

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on Misapplied economics and overwrought estimates · 2015-01-13T15:06:26.240Z · LW · GW

If just one consumer decided to not buy the good at any price this is what would happen.

Yes, I'm referring to a decrease in a consumer's purchases at any price (such as someone becoming vegetarian in a chicken market) not just at one price (in which case, if the price lowered a cent, they would re-enter the market); I agree this also counts as a decrease in demand.

The answer is that it depends, and the decrease in sales could be tiny or huge depending on elasticities.

Yes, if you mean 'long-run elasticities' then we agree. In fact the only thing that confuses me about your answer is what you think I should learn from an introductory microeconomics textbook.

The fall in demand will (by definition) have no impact on the supply curve since the supply curve takes into account how much firms are willing to sell at every price and so already accounts for the possibility of prices falling.

I disagree with your claim and it seems like you're confusing short-run and long-run; I don't think you'll find a definition of supply curve such that it cannot react to changes in demand in the long-run. Policonomics explains such a demand-motivated change in supply (D', S', and E2 refer to the chart in the original post):

Once this market equilibrium is reached, one might ask: what happens if there is an increase in demand? First, this will shift market demand to D’, increasing prices because supply (for the moment) is given. This increase in prices allows for profits to be made, at point 1. However, as seen before, these profits will attract new firms, which will force supply to the right (S’), going to an equilibrium such as E2, where our firm will produce the exact same initial quantity (point 2).

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-12T17:12:12.887Z · LW · GW

Based on the comments to this article I realized a stronger appeal to established economic theory would probably be more convincing. I've made that appeal in a separate post: http://lesswrong.com/r/discussion/lw/lj0/misapplied_economics_and_overwrought_estimates/

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-09T22:18:31.331Z · LW · GW

OK so you have no prior for large cases, you have no prior about the relationship between large cases and small cases, and your guess for small cases is "zero impact".

My prior for large cases is 1:1 impact, my prior is that the impact in large cases is proportionally similar to the impact in small cases, and therefore my prior for small cases is 1:1 impact.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-09T22:03:48.869Z · LW · GW

My "not buying a chicken" seems like it would look very similar to anyone else's "not buying a chicken".

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-09T20:54:25.494Z · LW · GW

Thanks for acknowledging that.

I think standard economics agrees with your vision of "~always positively-sloping finite supply curves" in the short term, but not necessarily the long term. Here's a quote from AmosWEB (OK, never heard of them before, but they had the quote I wanted)

As a perfectly competitive industry reacts to changes in demand, it traces out positive, negative, or horizontal long-run supply curve due to increasing, decreasing, or constant cost.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-09T12:52:39.451Z · LW · GW

Oops, I meant to edit that rather than retract. Since I don't believe there's a way to un-retract I'll re-paste it here with my correction (Changing "Supply Elasticity is 1" to "Supply Elasticity is finite"):

Cumulative elasticity = Supply Elasticity/(Supply Elasticity - Demand Elasticity). A cumulative elasticity factor of one means a demand elasticity of 0.

I believe your math skipped a step; it seems like you're assuming that Supply Elasticity is finite. I actually claim in the original article that "the 'price elasticity of supply' in the arbitrarily long term becomes arbitrarily high". In other words, as "length of 'term'" goes to infinity, the Supply Elasticity also goes to infinity and the cumulative elasticity factor approaches 1 for any finite Demand Elasticity.

Thanks for the math demonstrating my point.

Stepping back, I worry from your sarcastic tone and the reactive nature of your suggestions that you assume that I am trying to 'beat you' in a debate, and that by sharing information that helps your argument more than it helps mine, I have made a mistake worthy of mockery.

Instead, I am trying to share an insight that I believe is being overlooked by the 'conventional wisdom' of this community and is affecting multiple public recommendations for rational behavior (of cost/benefit magnitude ~2x).

If I am wrong, I would like to be shown to be so, and if you are wrong, I hope you also want to be corrected. If instead you're just debating for the sake of victory, then I don't expect you to ever be convinced, and I don't want to waste my effort.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-09T12:49:13.774Z · LW · GW

Cumulative elasticity = Supply Elasticity/(Supply Elasticity - Demand Elasticity). A cumulative elasticity factor of one means a demand elasticity of 0.

I believe your math skipped a step; it seems like you're assuming that Supply Elasticity is 1. I actually claim in the original article that "the 'price elasticity of supply' in the arbitrarily long term becomes arbitrarily high". In other words, as "length of 'term'" goes to infinity, the Supply Elasticity also goes to infinity and the cumulative elasticity factor approaches 1 for any finite Demand Elasticity.

Thanks for the math demonstrating my point.

Stepping back, I worry from your sarcastic tone and the reactive nature of your suggestions that you assume that I am trying to 'beat you' in a debate, and that by sharing information that helps your argument more than it helps mine, I have made a mistake worthy of mockery.

Instead, I am trying to share an insight that I believe is being overlooked by the 'conventional wisdom' of this community and is affecting multiple public recommendations for rational behavior (of cost/benefit magnitude ~2x).

If I am wrong, I would like to be shown to be so, and if you are wrong, I hope you also want to be corrected. If instead you're just debating for the sake of victory, then I don't expect you to ever be convinced, and I don't want to waste my effort.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-08T19:24:37.887Z · LW · GW

That question seems to have a simple answer: your decision will not affect the long-term production of chicken.

OK, so I argue option A, you state option B, and the articles I link argue option C.

That is a much more complicated question

I agree it's a complicated question (in that it requires lots of information to answer precisely and accurately). If you had no empirical data to work with, what would be your best guess/expectation? Also if your answer is proportionally different than in the 'single chicken' case, I'd be curious to know why.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-08T16:45:20.351Z · LW · GW

Right. In this case, to answer the question, "If I decide to reduce my lifetime consumption of chicken by one, should I expect the long term production of chicken to drop by ~1, ~0, or something in between?" Which is of demonstrated interest to the authors I am critiquing.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-08T16:31:50.708Z · LW · GW

What you are effectively claiming is that there are no suboptimal producers of chickens. Unless every producer of chickens is ideally located, ideally managed, ideally staffed, and working with ideal capital there are differences in production costs.

It's not that this will ever actually be the case, but the argument is that, in the long term, the market approaches what you would expect with such assumptions (and continues to have short term fluctuations away from that). But yes, even this assumption is clearly not actually true in all cases (as with all assumptions in neoclassical economics); the better question is whether it's a good simplification (enough to form a reasonable prior) or whether there is a better simplification we can consider (either simpler or more accurate).

The estimates I'm critiquing in the original post assume "short term elasticities are the best prior for long term elasticities" and I am advocating that "a better prior for the long term cumulative elasticity factor is 1".

There is a reason, that economics assumes that the amount of a good supplied changes as price changes, and I haven't seen any argument that exempts the case of chickens. Also, how does the market create less chickens as demand falls? If there are differences in cost, the highest cost producers leave the market as price falls. Easy to answer with the standard assumptions, but almost impossible with your nonstandard prior.

The explanation of both of these issues is the short term supply curve (which is not flat). In the short term, if people stop eating chicken, the price drops, and the producers that are (in the short term) able to improve their (expected long term) profits by scaling or shutting down do so.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-07T20:05:38.839Z · LW · GW

Empirical evidence is nice and often more convincing than theory, but I don't think it's necessary for an argument to be convincing (to believe otherwise would be quite... burdensome).

In this case, the original articles I am critiquing used purely theoretical arguments to claim that there will be long term price elasticity of supply, and I think that a theoretical critique is sufficient to show that the strength of their arguments is currently too weak to support the complexity of their theory.

I'm certainly open to any empirical evidence that may exist. Would you find a quick analysis of Big Macs moving (or if not, do you have a suggestion for a different empirical analysis)?

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-07T19:28:27.586Z · LW · GW

No, I haven't looked at the empirical evidence because I didn't think it would be as convincing as the 2 theoretical arguments I made in the original post; let me know if you are aware of any such analysis.

Would you accept the results we find from an analysis of Big Macs as relevant?

  • Since Big Macs aren't generally transported across national boundaries, we can think of the market for Big Macs in each country as largely independent.
  • While we would both expect various factors such as the price of labor to affect the price of Big Macs differently in each country, you would expect the price of Big Macs to positively correlate with # sold in that country (or possibly # sold per person), right? I would not expect such a correlation. (I think looking across countries is better than in one country across time, since then technology or other time-dependent factors would bias the results.)
  • If we had time we could control for all the other factors we don't want to bias the results like price of labor; but maybe even without these we might see some interesting initial patterns.
Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-07T18:48:39.237Z · LW · GW

In the specific example, they could be cloned by expanding in the good locations.

More generally, if you're claiming that there's a limited supply of good locations from which to produce chickens, then that reduces to a "finite inputs" argument I discuss in the last section of the OP. (For further discussion see responses to this comment .)

In short, I agree that such effects can create a sloping long term supply curve in some cases, but I also believe that there are other effects that can lead it to slope the opposite direction, and it's not immediately obvious which wins out. My prior is that the long term supply curve for an arbitrary product is virtually flat.

Said another way, if you're going to argue that the long term cost-per-widget is higher when producing 2X widgets than X widgets, then you have to argue that the effect of finite inputs outweighs gains to scale and other factors. I haven't seen such an argument generally or in the case of chickens.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-07T12:51:10.457Z · LW · GW

This is true in the short term, but in the long term, the dynamic changes for producers:

  • The producers that know how to make chickens for $8 scale up or their production strategy is replicated by others.
  • The marginal cost of production (and hence price) keeps falling until all producers are making no profit (relative to opportunity cost of capital)
  • The industry can scale up/down (in the long term) to meet changing demand, but it can't drive prices any lower. If prices were any higher the industry would scale up in the short term and keep expanding until the price fell back to the Cost in the long term.

The elasticity of the demand curve changes less than the supply curve in the super long term, but if you agree with me that the supply curve is virtually flat at that point, then the elasticity of the demand curve is negligible (because as the supply curve shifts left and right, the only point on the demand curve that matters is quantity @ price = Cost/Supply price).

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-06T23:19:49.315Z · LW · GW

I think your scenario is a good illustration of "finite inputs", which I listed as one of five example ways in which the long term supply curve may not actually be flat (at the end of the original article).

While I think that finite supply is a very real force (that, if strong enough, would create significant long term price elasticity of supply as you claim), the other four examples I mentioned also seem very real to me, and it's not obvious which ones win out for any particular industry.

If Cost always grew with industry size, products in big industries would always cost more than the same product from equivalent but smaller industries (where both supply and demand is reduced). Intuitively/anecdotally this doesn't seem to be true; I think the most common reasons it's not true are "gains to scale".

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-06T23:00:48.131Z · LW · GW

So what you are basically saying is that in the long run the price will be driven close to the lowest average price -- right?

Yes; in the long term the producers that have higher-than-average Costs will be driven out of the market.

Still not quite, as once you recognize that "perturbations" will happen, you need to engage in some risk management (zero mean does not imply zero volatility). In your scenario the chicken producer seems to be fine with the 50% chance of going bankrupt at the delivery time which isn't a good assumption to make.

I'm modeling risk management as part of the typical Cost of doing business, along with things like interest rates, opportunity costs of capital, chicken feed, other inputs, etc. Separating out risk management as a stand-alone variable doesn't seem to change anything.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-06T22:50:07.417Z · LW · GW

If the received wisdom is that a larger chicken industry will increase the price of chicken feed, then my prior is that it's true in the short term, but not the long term. Chicken feed might be in finite supply, in which case Cost might grow with chicken industry size, but there are other reasons I can imagine Cost might shrink with increasing chicken industry size (listed in original article) and I don't have enough confidence about any of these factors to break my prior that Cost at industry size 2X is ~Cost at industry size X.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-06T18:30:57.605Z · LW · GW

Huh? A flat supply curve means that the producers will produce the same number of chicken regardless of the price at which they can sell them. I don't see why this should be true in long term.

I mean "horizontal" rather than "vertical". In that sense, a flat supply curve means a constant price, not a constant quantity.

Not quite. You are implicitly assuming that the Cost is fixed in stone and it isn't. The chicken producer should accept all 10-year forwards on chicken if and only if he can buy matching forwards on his production inputs, otherwise he is exposed to the risk of, say, the price of feed going up.

I agree, but this is the type of pressure on Cost that I have no expectation of being in any particular direction. As a result, on expectation these perturbations average to zero, and the argument holds. It would be interesting if we had a reason to expect that Cost would go up or down depending on the amount of production. These are the issues my last section in the original article was intended to address.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on Why Eat Less Meat? · 2015-01-06T17:08:58.571Z · LW · GW

It's important to note that supply and demand aren't perfectly linear. If you reduce your demand for meat, the suppliers will react by lowering the price of meat a little bit, making it so more people can buy it. Since chickens dominate the meat market, we'll adjust by the supply elasticity of chickens, which is 0.22 and the demand elasticity of chickens, which is -0.52, and calculate the change in supply, which is 0.3. Taking this multiplier, it's more accurate to say you're saving 7.8 land animals a year or more. Though, there are a lot of complex considerations in calculating elasticity, so we should take this figure to have some uncertainty.

I think the calculations would be simpler and more accurate to assume that long term supply is in fact flat, so that eating one fewer animal causes ~one fewer to be produced in the long term. A more complete argument here.

If true, this would strengthen your overall point and make people even more empowered to reduce suffering!

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-06T15:46:02.271Z · LW · GW

One can be very modern and say that supply and demand curves are not real, but they are.

I'm not arguing that supply curves aren't real; I'm arguing that the super-long term supply curve is virtually flat (the price elasticity of supply is arbitrarily high). I find it compelling to imagine a chicken producer accepting contracts to produce chickens 10 years from now. At what prices and quantities would the producer accept the contracts? I would say it would accept all contracts at or above the Cost, at as high a quantity as possible. With lead time and certainty, the issues that create short term elasticity don't apply. (And yes, short term market shocks and uncertainties are real, but they're just built into the profitability model of Cost.)

the lower price will cause a switch towards chicken consumption among other people who were on the margin of demand.

Under the simplified assumptions we've been using, the starting price is the Cost of producing chicken. When the price drops in your scenario, that means chicken producers are operating at a loss. True they might not throw out any chickens if they appropriately adjust price, but they will not be satisfied with the new equilibrium (because the price is too low). Instead they will reduce production, let the price rise back to the starting point, and let the new chicken consumer (who values chicken at slightly less than Cost) drop back out of the market.

If you don't believe that the producers will keep reducing consumption until the price rises back to the original level and the "new consumers" (who value chicken < Cost) stop buying again, then you have to explain why producers aren't already producing more chickens than they are (in the absence of any dietary changes). In other words, if "new consumer" demand exists, and producers are still profitable with slightly lower prices, why haven't they scaled up production to larger than what it actually is today to sell chickens to "new consumers"?

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-06T14:43:55.801Z · LW · GW

Yes; another way to think of this is, "How do you model waste?"

  • If you think waste is best modeled by a fixed percentage of all production, then our best guess about the waste is that it changes proportionally with consumption. We don't get to magically assign our consumption to the 'waste' category without highly specific information (such as, "I found it in a dumpster").
  • If you expect the percentage of waste to grow/shrink with industry size, that could be an argument for slightly less/more than 1:1 effect (I'd put it in the "Gains to scale" category, even if it were negative). But I've never seen someone make that argument or attempt to model it.

Richard Chappell discusses a very simple model here.

Thanks for sending this; the 'chunky fallacy' comes up frequently when discussing this issue. Unfortunately, he explicitly endorses using short term elasticities at the end of his article.

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on How much does consumption affect production? · 2015-01-06T01:51:26.867Z · LW · GW

In your model, how can you tell how close a market is to reaching the thresholds you suggest? In other words, if we are somewhere in the middle of converting a "large swath" of the population to vegetarianism, how can we tell if we're at a point of 1 effect?

My guess is that we can't distinguish between those cases, in which case the best we can do is to average out over all long periods of time/market states and estimate that our long term effect is 1:1 (even though, in every case, it probably isn't exactly that).

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on Open thread, Dec. 29, 2014 - Jan 04, 2015 · 2015-01-05T15:57:00.896Z · LW · GW

Thanks to everyone who granted me karma! I just posted the article here: http://lesswrong.com/lw/lgy/how_much_does_consumption_affect_production/

Comment by Timothy Telleen-Lawton (erratim) on Open thread, Dec. 29, 2014 - Jan 04, 2015 · 2015-01-02T04:17:48.898Z · LW · GW

Hi, I've been following LW and the occasional article for a couple years but have never posted any comments. Now I'd like to post an article but I need 20 karma to do so. If you don't mind up-voting this comment to allow me to do that, please do!

If it helps, the post I've drafted is about some of the altruistic eating arguments I've seen in the broader LW network such as:

I use one neoclassical economic and one intuitive appeal to argue that they could all be simpler and more accurate by leaving out elasticities. LW seems like the perfect forum for this discussion!

Happy to share the draft privately before it's posted if that affects your desire to up-vote this comment, or any recommendations as to whether it's more appropriate for Main or Discussion.

Thanks!